Javatpoint Logo
Javatpoint Logo

What is Price Discrimination?

A marketing tactic known as price discrimination involves charging clients various rates for the same good or service depending on what the vendor believes they can persuade the customer to accept. When merchants use genuine price discrimination, they pay each consumer the highest price they agree to. In much more prevalent types of price discrimination, the supplier divides clients into groups based on distinct characteristics and assesses a different amount for each category.

What is Price Discrimination

Knowledge of Price Discrimination

The basis for price discrimination is the purchaser's conviction that specific groups of clients can be requested to pay higher or lower prices depending on their demographics or how much they value the products or services in question.

Price discrimination is still most beneficial when the revenue generated, and the benefit obtained from maintaining the marketplaces united is higher than the value of the commodities. The respective price elasticity in the subsectors determines whether price discrimination is effective and how long the various parties are willing to pay higher prices for the same commodity. Customers in a submarket- a market that is fairly inelastic pay more, whereas customers in a submarket that is unit elastic pay less.

Price discrimination allows a business seeking to increase sales to distinguish between market segments, such as home and industrial consumers, with various levels of price elasticity. Markets need to be maintained apart in terms of time, location, and type of use. For instance, educational institutions can purchase the Microsoft Office Education version for less money than commercial businesses for different uses.

The marketplaces cannot cross over such that buyers in the elastic sector of the market cannot resale in the inelastic sector of the market for a greater price. To increase the effectiveness of pricing discrimination, the corporation must also possess monopolistic power.

Price Discrimination Types

Price discrimination comes in three flavors: first-degree, often known as flawless price discrimination, 2nd, and 3rd. These levels of differential pricing are indeed referred to as group price, product version control, menu boards, and tailored pricing (1st-degree pricing) (3rd-degree pricing).

Price Discrimination in the First Degree

First-degree discrimination, often known as perfectly competitive, is when a company charges the highest price per unit of consumption. The company obtains all possible surplus value for either itself or the income received since prices fluctuate between units. First-degree price discrimination, in which a business charges a premium cost for each commodity or service sold, is a common practice in businesses involving customer service.

S Price Discrimination in the Second Degree

When a business charges various prices for distinct amounts consumed, such as through quantity discounts on expensive transactions, this is known as second-degree pricing discrimination.

Price Discrimination in the Third Degree

When a business charges cheaper fees to a certain customer base, it engages in third-degree price discrimination. As an illustration, a theatre might charge different rates for the same movie to elders, adults, and kids. The most typical form of discrimination is this.

Tariff in two halves

Another type of price discrimination is indeed the two-part tariff, in which the manufacturer levies an initial payment and a follow-up fee for the usage of the good. The outcome of this marketing technique is comparable to that of second-degree price discrimination. In the business of shaving razors, a two-part tariff price is an illustration.

The consumer first incurs the cost of the razor, and further costs for replacing blades are incurred. So because consumers have spent so far for the first blade container and therefore will continue to purchase the blades, which are less expensive than purchasing men's razors, this pricing plan works.

Circumstances

Even if price discrimination is among the best methods for increasing sales, not all businesses can use it. A company must meet specific standards or criteria. circumstances include: Monopoly of the Company

A company becomes the price setter when it controls the market. Because of market imperfections, businesses are free to choose such cost-cutting measures.

Market Division

Market segmentation is necessary for this pricing strategy to succeed. Therefore, businesses must segment the markets according to a variety of criteria, such as youth, gender, tastes, geographical barriers, product kind, timing, etc. Businesses can use dynamic pricing methods according to the time of purchase or the demand for a particular item, depending on this divide.

The market groups should be split out so that, at all costs, no two sectors get intertwined. The convenience of reselling would result from the seepage of one sector into another. As a consequence, the companies who bought the products and resell them for less would begin to attract direct clients, causing the initial suppliers to suffer significant losses. Therefore, it's crucial to limit chances for resale.

Demand Elasticity

Moreover, a major factor in deciding whether price discrimination would be successful for a business is the elasticity of demand. For instance, a group with reduced money looks for solutions that require less outlay, which causes them to restrict their choices to be flexible. On the contrary, the higher-income groups are willing to spend extra, so they are more demanding and flexible with their alternatives.

A real pricing strategy may well be ineffective owing to the lower income group's levels of demand elasticity, but it might be successful due to higher income classes' inelastic demand.

Several examples of price discrimination exist.

  1. When it comes to marriages, the provider of the services and items may pay a little bit more than usual in order to profit from the occasion.
  2. Retailers who purchase in bulk may be subject to a different pricing strategy from those who purchase in smaller numbers from the distributors of the items and services. For instance, they might provide heavy discounts for large orders.
  3. Many companies, including the airline, theater, and medical sectors, employ pricing discrimination techniques. Coupon distribution, the use of particular discounts (such as age coupons), and the development of loyalty programs are a few examples of price discrimination. The airline sector offers one instance of price discrimination. When booking plane tickets in advance, buyers often spend less than those who wait until the last moment. Airlines increase ticket costs when a certain flight is in high demand.

On the opposite side, when the sale of flight tickets isn't going well, the airline lowers the price of the remaining seats to boost sales. Due to the fact that many travelers choose to return home on Sundays, those flights are higher priced than those departing earlier Sunday early. Additionally, extra legroom is often priced higher for airline travelers.

In the scenario of an apartment, the square foot price in one location could be very high because of the location's amenities and availability. In contrast, an identical flat might cost less in another neighborhood.

Price discrimination: Is it illegal?

The term "discrimination" in pricing unequal treatment often does not refer to anything wrong or offensive. Conversely, it relates to businesses' ability to flexibly alter the prices of goods or activities in response to shifting market conditions, charge various customers differently for the same services, or maintain a single price for goods with varying costs. Either method is illegal in the United States; it would only be considered illegal if it results in any harm to the law or person in the country.

Current Taxonomy

Pigou is responsible for the first-, second-, and third-degree price discrimination taxonomies. These divisions, meanwhile, are neither mutually exhaustive nor exhaustive. Ivan Png offers an alternate taxonomy.

Full discrimination occurs when a supplier sets a different price for each unit, causing each customer to buy until their marginal utility is equal to the marginal cost of the good; Direct Segmentation, in which the vendor can base the pricing on a buyer-specific characteristic (such as age or sexual identity);

indirect segmentation, where the vendor structures a decision that indirectly separates the purchasers based on some substitute (e.g., box size, use quantity, discount); Uniform Pricing, in which the vendor establishes a single price for every single product item.

Complete, direct, indirect, and uniform pricing is ranked in highest to the lowest of efficiency and data need. Full price discrimination is the most successful investment, but it also necessitates the vendor having the most knowledge about the customers. Direct segmentation is the second most lucrative and information-required and is preceded by indirect segmentation. Last but not least, consistent pricing is the least effective and necessitates the supplier knowing the least about the customers.

Consumers would benefit more if everyone paid the same price, right?

No, in many instances. The attributes and price points that different client segments are willing to pay vary. Individuals at lower price ranges would never be able to afford it if all items were sold at, say, the "average cost." Those who can afford it more could hoard it as well. This is what market segmentation entails. Deficiencies in the market can result in both the sides of supply and demand when prices are fixed at a certain level, according to market mechanisms described by economists.

When Can Businesses Use Price Discrimination Effectively?

Price discrimination cannot occur unless three conditions are met, according to experts. The business must first possess enough market strength. Second, it needs to pinpoint variations in variations in demand according to various circumstances or consumer groups. Third, the company must be able to prevent its goods from being transferred to different consumer groups.

The Motive for Price Discrimination

Price discrimination often aims to seize the oversupply of customers on the market. This excess results from the fact that some buyers (the group with very low-cost elasticity) would have been ready to pay higher than the single cost price in a market with such a single clearing price. A portion of this surplus is transferred from the customer to the producer/marketer through price discrimination. It is a strategy to boost monopolistic profit. In a market with perfect competition, firms can't discriminate on price because they make basic profits rather than monopolistic profits.

One could claim that technically accurately, there is no need for additional profits in situations where, for instance, scale economies or fixed costs result in a situation where the marginal cost of acquiring more customers is lower than the relative profit generated by selling more goods.

This indicates that it may be advantageous to charge some customers less than an equal share of costs. High-speed internet access shared between two customers in the same building is an example of how price discrimination can enable the purchase.

If one customer is prepared to pay at least half the price of linking the building while the other is eager to make up the difference but not the full amount, the acquisition can go through. But this will cost customers the same amount or maybe higher than if they gathered their resources to pay a fair price. A marginal benefit goes to the occupants if the structure is considered the customer.

Profit from Discrimination in pricing

  • Enables a failing company to avoid bankruptcy.

In some circumstances, it's possible that no single price would allow a business to achieve typical profits. Average prices would always be greater than the demand curve. Therefore, the firm might transform a loss into a modest profit using price discrimination.

This indicates that a commercial activity may continue rather than the end. Customers will undoubtedly benefit from this since it broadens their selection of products and services. Train services are one instance. Train operators without differential pricing between off-peak and bit higher ke a greater loss and might be stopped.

  • Cost savings are advantageous to some individuals.

Price discrimination occurs when businesses are incentivized to lower prices for certain categories of price-sensitive customers (elastic demand). For instance, businesses frequently give students a 10% discount. Due to their relatively smaller incomes, youngsters' demand is much more flexible. They gain from decreased prices as a result. These populations frequently have lower incomes than the average user. The drawback is that some customers will pay more.

  • Avoid Traffic.

Managing demand through price discrimination is one strategy. Rush-hour carriages would become more packed if there were no price discrimination. Price discrimination encourages some customers to shop earlier in the day. As a result, those who make a greater loss might be stopped.

  • Cost savings are advantageous to some groups.

Price discrimination who must travel during rush hour profit from decreased traffic. Customers with low incomes could profit from lower prices. The practice of giving customers who accumulate coupons discounted pricing is one case of indirect price discrimination. This results in a cost to the consumer (time to collect). Therefore, customers who are time-rich but cash-poor can benefit from decreased prices.

  • The incentive to invest.

Price discrimination aids in a company's increased profitability. The business could be capable of investing in more equipment as a result. For instance, an airline that maximizes revenues through pricing discrimination may decide to invest in modernizing its fleet of planes with cutting-edge equipment.

Price Discrimination Drawbacks

  • Higher costs: As previously mentioned, some consumers will pay less, whereas others will pay more. Customers who must pay more (namely, those who buy plane tickets during the busiest time) are at a loss.
  • Quantity produced is decreased by the pricing approach, which also transfers funds from customers to employers, creating inequality.
  • Possibly unjust. Higher price-payers might not always be the wealthiest people. Youngsters paying full price, for instance, could be jobless, while seniors could be extremely wealthy.
  • The expense of administration. Dividing the marketplaces will incur administrative overhead, which can result in higher prices.
  • Extortionate prices. Exploitative pricing might be financed with the proceeds from differential pricing. The monopolistic authority required to value can be maintained by predatory pricing.

Pricing discrimination caused by gender

Whenever one gender is offered a different amount over another for the same products or services, this is referred to as gender-based pricing discrimination. There is also price discrimination based on ethnicity and class. Although discriminatory acts frequently result in legal repercussions, research on gender-based pricing discrimination first examines gendered price differences.

From there, a legal inquiry might be established by looking at the rules of the relevant jurisdiction to determine whether gender-specific price differences prove a purpose to discrimination or constitute unlawful discrimination. Generally speaking, although not generally, gender-based price discrimination is not acceptable.

All over the United States, these discriminations are still going on, which is creating an issue in marketing policies. Few countries in the US have passed legislation against gender-based differential pricing, but these laws are rarely applied. Price differences typically have a larger negative impact on women than on males. For instance, according to research by both the New York State Department of Customer and Workers Rights, the mean price of a product for a woman is 7% higher than the price of a competitive product for a man.

Many businesses, like healthcare, laundry service, hair salons, nightclubs, clothes, and products for personal care, have gender-based prices. Ever since the 1990s, the validity of gender-based price discrimination in corresponding marketplaces has been a topic of discussion in the US and the EU. The main topic of discussion is not whether gender-based purchasing constitutes gender discrimination. In those other words, the gender-based price may promote harmful perceptions about these women & men in pairing rather than prices being established on a business examination of the consequences of the competition in the market.

Costs for customer experience, retail sales, and products for personal care have been discovered to differ by gender. They can also be seen in insurance costs for things like health and auto insurance. Some studies contend that while negotiating and buying new cars, gender-based price differences frequently take place.

Reduced rates based on one's gender may also constitute a form of price discrimination based on sex. A "ladies' night" advertisement, where female customers pay very little for alcoholic beverages or a reduced entrance fee than male customers, is a typical example of a gender-based pricing discount.

Consumer taxes on some goods but not another have been seen as a kind of pricing based on gender discrimination. Tampons, for instance, are frequently consumed in the United States, Australia, as well as the United Kingdom.

Examples

The behavior of imposing different costs for the same or comparable services and goods when the manufacturing cost is comparable for men and women is known as gender-based price discrimination.

Gender-based discrimination has long been a topic of discussion in the US. The 1992 study into "pricing bias against women in the marketplace" was carried out by the New York City Department of Consumer Affairs ("DCA"). According to the DCA's analysis, women paid more at used vehicle dealerships, dry cleaners, and beauty salons than males did.

The gender-based price discrimination that affects women financially was raised to the media spotlight by the DCA's investigation into gender prices in New York City.

Asymmetric pricing for consumer goods is typically not dependent on the buyer's identified gender but is performed subtly through the use of unique packaging, branding, or color combinations aimed at appealing to male or female customers. When a product is sold as an appealing gift, it happens frequently that the buyer's sexuality differs from the ultimate user's.

The California Assembly's Department of Research investigated the topic of service price discrimination by gender in 1995 and calculated that women in California paid a "sexual identity tax" of around $1,351.00 per year for comparable services as males. According to estimates, women spend far more on similar goods than men do throughout their lives.







Youtube For Videos Join Our Youtube Channel: Join Now

Feedback


Help Others, Please Share

facebook twitter pinterest

Learn Latest Tutorials


Preparation


Trending Technologies


B.Tech / MCA